I imagine what I want to write in my case, I write it in the search engine and I get exactly what I wanted. Thank you!
Valentina R., lawyer
EN
Only the English text is available and authentic.
Office for Official Publications of the European Communities L-2985 Luxembourg
SG (2003) D/232960
In the published version of this decision, some information has been omitted pursuant to Article 17(2) of Council Regulation (EEC) No 4064/89 concerning non-disclosure of business secrets and other confidential information. The omissions are shown thus [Ö]. Where possible the information omitted has been replaced by ranges of figures or a general description.
To the Notifying Party
Dear Sir/Madam,
1.On 29.09.2003 the Commission received a notification of a proposed concentration pursuant to Article 4 of Council Regulation (EEC) No 4064/89(ìthe ìMerger Regulationî) by which Sydkraft AB (ìSydkraftî, Sweden), belonging to the German E.ON Group (ìE.ONî), acquires within the meaning of Article 3(1)(b) of the Council Regulation sole control of the whole of the undertaking Graninge AB (ìGraningeî, Sweden), by way of purchase of shares.
2.After examination of the notification, the Commission has concluded that the notified operation falls within the scope of Council Regulation (EEC) No 4064/89 and does not raise serious doubts as to its compatibility with the common market and with the EEA Agreement.
1OJ L 395, 30.12.1989 p. 1; corrigendum OJ L 257 of 21.9.1990, p. 13; Regulation as last amended by Regulation (EC) No 1310/97 (OJ L 180, 9. 7. 1997, p. 1, corrigendum OJ L 40, 13.2.1998, p. 17).
Commission europÈenne, B-1049 Bruxelles / Europese Commissie, B-1049 Brussel - Belgium. Telephone: (32-2) 299 11 11.
3.Sydkraft is an energy company active in inter alia the fields of electricity, natural gas and district heating, mainly in Sweden but also in Finland. E.ON holds 55% of the shares in Sydkraft ; the Norwegian state-owned energy company Statkraft holds 45%.
4.Graninge is an energy company active in the fields of electricity and district heating in Sweden and Finland. The French energy company EletricitÈ de France (ìEDFî) holds 36.3% of the shares in Graninge, two families hold together 17.5% and Sydkraft holds 36.4%. EDF and the two families have joint control over Graninge through a shareholdersí agreement.
5.Sydkraft acquires EDFís shareholding in Graninge and will hold 72.7% of the shares, thus gaining sole control over Graninge.
6.In the light of the above, it can be concluded that the operation constitutes a concentration within the meaning of article 3(1)(b) of the Merger Regulation.
7.The undertakings concerned have a combined aggregate world-wide turnover of more than EUR 5 billion (EUR 37,196 million for E.ON Group and EUR 370.4 million for Graninge). Each of E.ON Group and Graninge have a Community-wide turnover in excess of EUR 250 million [EURÖ.] million for E.ON Group and [EURÖ.] million for Graninge), but they do not achieve more than two-thirds of their aggregate Community-wide turnover within one and the same Member State (E.ON achieved more than two thirds of its community-wide turnover in Germany and Graninge achieved more than two thirds of its community-wide turnover in Sweden). The notified operation therefore has a Community dimension.
2See Commission decision of 9.4.2001 in case No M.2349 ñ E.ON/Sydkraft.
3See Commission decision of 25.5.1998 in case No M.1169 ñ EDFI/Graninge.
4Turnover calculated in accordance with Article 5(1) of the Merger Regulation and the Commission Notice on the calculation of turnover (OJ C66, 2.3.1998, p. 25). To the extent that figures include turnover for the period before 1.1.1999, they are calculated on the basis of average ECU exchange rates and translated into EUR on a one-for-one basis.
2
8.The Nordic electricity market ñ comprising Norway, Sweden, Denmark and Finland ñ is fully liberalised and connected through interconnectors. Anyone connected to any part of a national network in Denmark, Finland, Norway and Sweden can in principle buy (or sell) electricity from (to) anyone else connected to the network.
9.The total production of electricity in the Nordic countries amounts to approximately 380-390 TWh per year (of which Sweden accounts for approximately 40%, Norway 30%, Finland 20% and Denmark 10%).
10.Electricity is transmitted from power stations to consumers through a network of power lines (national grids, regional networks and local networks). The consumption and production of electricity must be in balance at every instant, which is achieved by balance control. There is a transmission system operator (ìTSOî) in every country who is responsible for (i) the task of maintaining this balance, and (ii) the national grid.
11.Electricity prices are determined by supply and demand in the Nordic market. Nord Pool ñ the Nordic Power Exchange ñ is the central market place for sales and purchases of electricity in the Nordic region. Nord Pool operates the following market places: (i) Elspot (market for physical trading of electricity for next day delivery); (ii) Elbas (continuous physical market for balance purposes, i.e. trade in electricity closer to delivery time than Elspot); (iii) Eltermin (financial market for price hedging and risk management when buying and selling electricity power); and (iv) Eloptions (financial market for risk management and for forecasting future income and costs related to trade in electricity contracts). Nord Pool also offers a clearing services for power traded over the counter (OTC) and bilaterally.
12.It is at Nord Poolís Elspot market where the daily electricity price (the ìsystem priceî) is set based on the interception of the aggregated supply and demand curves derived from daily bids from all the market players in the Nordic countries. During normal periods when there is no congestion (bottlenecks) in the inter-Nordic transmission network, the Nordic countries constitute one price area. During periods with bottlenecks, Nord Pool splits the market into separate price areas with different prices. In 2002, the Nordic Region was a single price area 35% of the time. The rest of the time, the Nordic Region was subdivided into different constellations of smaller price areas.
13.The proposed transaction will lead to horizontal overlaps between the partiesí activities in (i) generation and wholesale of electricity, (ii) regulation power, (iii) financial energy trading, (iv) transmission and distribution of electricity, (v) supply of electricity to end-users, (vi) district heating, and (vii) supply of gas.
3
14.The Commission has in previous decisions considered the generation and wholesale of electricity to constitute one separate product market. This encompasses the production of electricity at power stations as well as electricity physically imported through interconnectors.
15.Sydkraft considers electricity production as a separate product market for the following reasons. Electricity production may be regarded as the first part of the ìvalue chainî of the market for production and wholesale supply of electricity. The production of electricity is required to take place in a separate legal entity from the delivery of electricity to end-users. The production is sold on a wholesale market either to traders, distribution companies or large industrial end-users.
16.Electricity can be traded on the wholesale market in a number of ways. At the bilateral market electricity is traded directly between a seller and buyer up to several years before the operating hour.
17.Elspot is an auction-based spot market for trade in power contracts for physical delivery where hourly power contracts are traded daily for physical delivery in the next dayís 24-hours period. According to Nord Poolís annual report, in 2002, the volume of contracts traded via the Elspot market was 123.6 TWh, equivalent to 32% of the electricity consumption in the Nordic countries. This means that 68% of all physically traded electricity was traded outside the Nord Pool.
18.The Elbas market is an after-market for Elspot that allows the participants to settle contracts after the Elspot market has closed and until one hour before the operating hour. Due to the time span of up to 36 hours between Elspot price-fixing and delivery, participants use this market to improve their balance of physical contracts.
19.The Commissionís market investigation confirmed that generation and wholesale of electricity constitutes a separate product market. The market encompasses electricity sold on bilateral contract as well as electricity sold on Elspot and Elbas. The main reason being that producers would easily be able to substitute between these different markets in reaction to permanent price differences.
20.However, for the purpose of this decision the precise product market definition can be left open, since the transaction will not lead to competition concerns.
21.While the bilateral contracts require both parties to reside in the same country, Elspot allows for exchange of electricity between countries. Elspot sets the system price based on the interception of the aggregated supply and demand curves derived from bids from all the market players in the Nordic countries.
5See Commission decisions of 25.7.2002 in case No COMP/M. 2890 ñ EDF/Seeboard and of 18.12.2002 in case No COMP/M. 3007 ñ E.ON/TXU-Europe Group, respectively.
22.When production and consumption is sufficiently asymmetric, a fully integrated market is impeded by congestions in the network. Elspotís price mechanism is used to regulate the flow of power where there are capacity restrictions in the overall Nordic grid. When congestions develop, two or more area prices are created, with high prices in areas where consumption is higher than production and low prices in areas with a production surplus. By reducing or increasing area prices, the power flow is altered until it matches allocated grid capacity.
23.The permanent price areas in which Nord Pool can devise different prices are: Sweden, Finland, Denmark West (DK1), Denmark East (DK2), South Norway (NO1) and Middle/North Norway (NO2). These may become separate price areas if the contractual flow of power between bid areas exceeds the capacity allocated for Elspot contracts by TSOs.
24.Sydkraft considers the geographic scope of the generation/wholesale market to encompass at the very least the Nordic countries (Denmark, Finland, Norway and Sweden). Sydkraft submits that in hours with no congestion on the network, prices are identical in all the Nordic countries and the Nordic area is an integrated geographic market. The distribution of price areas within the Nordic area and the frequency with which they occur varies from year to year primarily due to variations in weather conditions (precipitation and cold). In 2001, the Nordic region was one single price area 652% of the time. The corresponding figure for 2002 was 35%.
25.Electricity is a product, which cannot be stored and must therefore be consumed in the same instant as it is produced. Combined with a limited possibility of substitutability between different time periods different geographic electricity, markets can be distinguished by the time at which the electricity is delivered. As indicated above congestion on the transmission network can cause the Nordic electricity market to split into separate price areas. This limits the number of suppliers able to supply electricity in a given area and thereby the competitive structure of the market.
26.Considering these dynamic aspects of the geographic market, the Commission has investigated the frequency and distribution of the different price areas of the Nordic electricity market. The Commission has considered the number of hours in which Sweden has been isolated from the rest of the Nordic area. In 2000, Sweden was isolated from the other areas 5.5% of the time. In 2001, it was isolated 0.0%, 0.1% in 2002 and 0.0% in January-September 2003. This implies that Sweden mostly is a part of a larger market. Considering neighbouring areas, the price in Sweden was the same price as in Finland 84.2% of the time in 2000, 99.1% in 2001, 95.0% in 2002 and 70.2% in 2003.
Based on this, it is clear that Sweden has only constituted a separate geographic area during an insignificant period of time in each of the last years. At the same time the
6ìA Powerful Competition Policyî, a report from the Nordic competition authorities, June 2003.
7See also the report ìRelevant markets in the Nordic areaî, Copenhagen Economics, 21 October 2002. The report is available on www.nordel.org.
8Based on figures supplied by Nord Pool.
The price correlation between Sweden and Finland and Sweden and Denmark seems to imply that the generation/wholesale market is likely to be larger than Sweden. However, for the purpose of this decision, the precise scope of the geographic market can be left open, since the transaction will not create competition concerns on any alternative assumption.
28.Considering a Nordic market for the generation of electricity, the proposed transaction will not give rise to an affected market. The parties combined market share was [5 ñ 10]% (Sydkraft [5 ñ 10]%, Graninge [0 ñ 5]%) in 2002. Their largest competitor, Vattenfall, holds a market share of [15 ñ 20]% and Statkraft a market share of [10 ñ 15]%. Looking at a separate Swedish market for the generation of electricity the parties would hold a share of total production of [20 ñ 25]% (Sydkraft [15 ñ 20]%, Graninge [0 ñ 5]%). In comparison the largest Swedish producer Vattenfall would hold a market share of [45 ñ 50]%, Fortum [15 ñ 20]% and a number of smaller generators with [0 ñ 5]% each. In Finland the partiesí activities will be minor. Sydkraftís parent company E.ON is active on the Finnish market and has a market share of approximately [0 ñ 5]% of electricity production. Graninge is also active on the Finnish market with a market share of [0 ñ 5]%.
When the dynamic aspects of the geographic market are considered, the partiesí market shares based on production are as follows:
SwedenSweden andSweden,Sweden andSweden and2002 andDenmarkFinland andTroms¯ Oslo FinlandEastDenmark East
Sydkraft [10 ñ 15]% [15 ñ 20]% [10 ñ 15]% [15 ñ 20]% [10 ñ 15]%
Graninge [0 ñ 5]% [0 ñ 5]% [0 ñ 5]% [0 ñ 5]% [0 ñ 5]%
Total
Both Sydkraft and Graninge are active on the wholesale market for electricity. Electricity is traded on Elspot, and to a large extent bilaterally. The bilateral trade takes place outside Elspot.
Sydkraft estimates the total consumption in the Nordic wholesale market to have been [105 ñ 115] TWh in 2002. However, the total consumption in the wholesale market is smaller than total sales since electricity suppliers and traders resell large volume of the electricity to customers in the end-use market. Consumers of electricity on the wholesale market are large industrial customers.
In the Nordic countries, Sydkraftís electricity sales in 2002 totalled [30 ñ 40] TWh, of which approximately [15 ñ 25] TWh on the wholesale market. By comparison Graninge sold [0 ñ 10] TWh on the Nordic wholesale market. Sydkraft cannot estimate the total
9Looking at the total installed capacity figures the parties will control [20 ñ 25]%, Vattenfall [40 ñ 45]% and Fortum [15 ñ 20]%. The remaining [10 ñ 15]% are divided between a number of smaller competitors.
sales volume on the wholesale supply market. Sydkraft estimates its share of the Nordic wholesale market to be approximately [5 ñ 15]%. Graningeís sales are concentrated to sales to the end-user market. Its share of the Nordic wholesale market is estimated below [0 ñ 10]%
Considering a separate Swedish wholesale market for electricity Sydkraft sold a total of [30 ñ 40] TWh in Sweden in 2002. Out of this total around [10 ñ 20] TWh were sold in the wholesale market. Graninge sold a total of [0 ñ 10] TWh in 2002, of which [0 ñ 10] TWh on the wholesale market. Based on this Sydkraft estimates its market share in 2002 on wholesale market in Sweden to have been [10 ñ 20]% and Graningeís [0 ñ 10]%. Sydkraft estimates Vattenfall to hold a market share of [45 ñ 55]%, Fortum approximately [10 ñ 20]%, Skellefte Kraft around [0 ñ 10]% and J‰mtkraft [0 ñ 10]%
Both partiesí activities on the Finnish market are limited. Sydkraft estimates E.ON Finland to hold a [0 ñ 10]% share of the wholesale market and Graninge [0 ñ 10]%
35.The report from the Nordic competition authorities concluded that the deregulation of the Nordic electricity sector has largely been successful, but that some obstacles to competition remain. These obstacles include the very inelastic demand, the high barriers to entry, the inflexible production facilities as well as the grid bottlenecks. Based on these findings, the authorities recommended that all mergers leading to increased market share be carefully reviewed.
36.The Commissionís findings in this case are in line with the conclusions of the report. The highly inelastic demand has as a consequence that any exercise of market power could be highly profitable and lead to significant consumer harm. In addition, the barriers to entry and the inherent capacity constraints reduce the possibility for competitive responses to such an exercise of market power. In these circumstances market power could emerge and result in consumer harm at relatively lower concentration levels than in many other markets.
37.Eltra ñ the local grid operator in Western Denmark ñ has developed a market simulation model (MARS) that makes it possible to simulate the effect of changes in the market structure on the electricity prices. For the purpose of analysing the current transaction, Eltra agreed to perform a number of simulations for the Commission. In its report to the Commission, Eltra concluded when comparing the outcome with and without the merger, îIt appears from market power simulations with MARS that the merger between Sydkraft and Graninge does not result in higher average prices in Swedenî. The simulations indicate that Sydkraft prior to the merger is not sufficiently large to have the incentive to withhold capacity in order to generate a price increase. This absence of market power is not significantly altered by the acquisition of Graninge.
Though simulation models, such as MARS, cannot fully take into account all the relevant details of the market situation, the simulation results are in line with the general results of the market investigation.
The electricity market has a number of features that prima facia indicates that competition could potentially be significantly impeded through co-ordinated behaviour. In general three conditions are necessary for a finding of collective dominance based on tacit co-ordination:
each member of the dominant oligopoly must have the ability to know how the other members are behaving. There must be sufficient market transparency for all members of the dominant oligopoly to be aware, sufficiently precisely and quickly, of the way in which the other members' market conduct is evolving;
the situation of tacit co-ordination must be sustainable over time; that is to say, there must be an incentive not to depart from the common policy on the market; and
the foreseeable reaction of current and future competitors, as well as of consumers, would not jeopardise the results expected from the common policy.
A finding of a risk of collusion would inter alia have to rely on proof of the following market features:
the product is very homogeneous;
the price-setting part of the transactions takes place on an exchange with a fairly high degree of transparency;
interaction is very frequent;
capacity restrictions lead to stable market shares and limits the scope for smaller players to disturb co-ordination by a tight oligopoly;
barriers to entry prevents co-ordination being disturbed by new entrants;
some production facilities are co-owned or otherwise shared by several producers.
In principle two different types of co-ordination could be envisaged. One where the oligopoly were to include all the large players in the Nordic region and one where co-ordination takes place amongst the Swedish operators (perhaps including the large operators in the most connected regions, such as Denmark East and Finland).
The first type of scenario appears likely to encounter difficulties given the fairly large number of relatively asymmetric operators. A more geographically limited oligopoly would be much more symmetric in terms of types of production facilities. Sydkraft, Vattenfall and Fortum are all active in both hydro-, thermal and nuclear production although with different volumes. It should be noted that a geographically more limited oligopoly would only be able to effectively influence prices in those periods where the relevant region due to bottlenecks is shielded from external competition.
A finding that the notified transaction raises serious doubts regarding the creation of a collective dominant position would require that the disappearance of Graninge significantly increases the risk of co-ordination in the market. In principle, even a small firm can, through its particular characteristics, be an aggressive competitive factor and act as a so-called ìmaverickî, preventing an oligopoly from successfully co-ordinating.
In this particular case, though, there are no indications that Graninge would be likely to be in a position to play such a role. This is mainly due to its capacity constraint. In a hypothetical situation with high prices due to insufficient capacity on the market, Graninge would not have any different incentives from other producers or, the possibility to lastingly increase its output with a view to establishing a higher market share.
Similarly, the Commission has not found that the acquisition of Graninge would significantly influence Sydkraftís incentives to co-ordinate.
Notwithstanding the overall risk of co-ordination in the market, the Commission has thus not found any reasons why this particular transaction would significantly alter the likelihood or scope for co-ordination. Consequently it is unlikely that Graninge's disappearance from the market would materially affect the risk of co-ordination in the market.
46.The regulating power market is a market for flexibility securing the overall functioning of the electricity system. Only a limited number of suppliers are active on the market for regulating power, since they must comply with certain demands and must be able to adjust their production with short notice. To authorise an operator to supply regulating power, the Swedish TSO requires a guarantee for the economic liability; that the bids be of at least 10 MW and at most 500 MW; and that the balance be regulated within 10 minutes. For upward regulation (i.e. need for higher production) the balance provider must be able to increase production at short notice. Likewise, if the system requires downward regulation (i.e. too high production), producers must lower their production or customers must increase their consumption. It requires a high degree of flexibility and available capacity to operate in this market. This is confirmed when considering the high amount of regulating power obtained from Norway, since the flexibility inherent in the production of hydro power makes it very suitable for regulation power. However, the need for regulating power is not known in advance but depends on the actual functioning of the electricity system. Based on this the market for regulating power shows specific characteristics, which separates this market from the general wholesale market.
47.Svenska Kraftn‰t is responsible for planning and co-ordinating the national balance between the production and consumption of electricity, as well as overseas exchange. Since it is impossible to store electricity there has to be a continuous balance between production and consumption to keep a stable frequency. The market players must make sure that they manage their balances. However, in practice deviations arise between the contracted and actual supply and demand, and these deviations must be balanced and settled. The balance management comprises a balance service that in the hour of operation creates a balance between production and consumption, and an imbalance settlement that follows after the 24-hour period of operation. The TSOs buy regulation power to cover the imbalances of the market players.
13The frequency of the system, which is a measure of its balance, must normally lie within a specific range around 50.0 Hz (+/- 0.1 Hz).
48.Balance regulation is carried out by way of primary regulation and secondary regulation. Primary regulation means that the physical balance in the system is adjusted by automatically increasing or decreasing of the production in a number of power plants. A Nordic agreement between the TSOs sets out the level of regulation effect to be held in store for primary regulation by each country. Svenska Kraftn‰t is to procure 2,400 MW/Hz out of the total demand of the Nordic system of 6,000 MW/Hz.
49.Secondary balance regulation is a manual adjustment upwards or downwards of regulation objects and is carried out through power trades with the balance providers that have signed agreements with Svenska Kraftn‰t to take part in the balance regulation. Secondary regulation is used when the primary regulation is not sufficient and is aimed at restoring the primary regulation whose task it is inter alia to be a reserve in case of sudden disruptions in the power system. Primary regulation is for the most part procured nationally yet its price follows the price for secondary regulation, which in turn is determined by bids from suppliers in all the Nordic countries.
50.Sydkraft considers the balance regulation market to form a part of the overall wholesale market. This is in line with a study by Copenhagen Economics. This argument is built on two main reasons. First, that supply substitution is feasible and likely to be swift, so that prices on one of the markets cannot rise significantly without generators quickly moving capacity from the other three markets (Elspot, Elbas and regulating power market). Secondly, that there may be some demand substitution between the bilateral market and the spot market.
51.The market investigation indicates that balance regulation may constitute a separate product market. However, for the purpose of this decision it can be left open whether balance regulation constitutes a separate product market as well as whether primary and secondary balance regulation constitute separate segments within this product market, since the proposed transaction will not create any competition concerns under either market definition.
52.The regulating power markets in the Nordic countries were combined in September 2002. The balance of the synchronous part of the Nordic electricity market is now controlled based on the frequency. Bids for regulating power in all the countries are compiled in a merit order list available to all Nordic TSOs in a common information system NOIS (Nordic Operational Information System). The TSOs in Norway and Sweden maintain the frequency by making common decisions to upward or downward regulate, by activating the bids from the common list. If the grid is congested the regulation necessary to alleviate the bottlenecks are made first, followed by regulation of the frequency. Bids are activated in the merit order to secure the lowest price possible for the regulating power.
14ìRelevant markets in the Nordic areaî, Copenhagen Economics, 21 October 2002. The report is available on www.nordel.org.
15ìCommon Balance Management in the Nordic Countriesî, special print of the feature article in Nordelís 2002 report.
53.Svenska Kraftn‰t procures around 2,400 MW/Hz of capacity for primary regulation. The procurement of the majority of this capacity is made from Swedish suppliers, for the reason that Svenska Kraftn‰t is responsible for the Swedish market. However, a part of the capacity for primary regulation in Sweden is supplied by Statnett Norge and Fingrid Finland.
54.Statistics from Svenska Kraftn‰t for the period September 2002ñAugust 2003 show that Norway was the largest provider of both upward and downward regulating power in the Nordic area. Norway accounted for around 50% of the total regulating power market in the Nordic area. This high figure is based on low regulating power prices based on cheap hydropower. By comparison, Swedenís share of the total Nordic regulation market was around 30%. It has not been possible to obtain information about the actual flow of regulating power between the Nordic countries. However, figures from Svenska Kraftn‰t show a considerable trade. In the period September 2002 - August 2003, Svenska Kraftn‰t sold regulating power for more than 176.9 MSEK and bought for around 358.5 MSEK.
55.For the purpose of this decision the precise scope of the geographic market can be left open, since the transaction will not lead to competition concerns on either a national or a Nordic basis.
- Sweden
56.Svenska Kraftn‰t estimates the Swedish part of the overall regulation market to be 1.346 MSEK and around 5.7 million MWh in 2002. These figures comprise both regulation power and balancing power. Regulating power is used to maintain the balance of the frequency of the total power system, whereas balancing power is used to cover the deviations between contracted and actual supply and demand of each player.
57.Svenska Kraftn‰t procures primary regulation in two phases of packages of 20MW/Hz. According to Sydkraft, Svenska Kraftn‰tís annual cost of primary regulation procurement has varied between 50-200 MSEK per year. According to information from Svenska Kraftn‰t Sydkraft and Graninge had a combined market share of around [20 ñ 30]% in 2002. Since September 2002 the TSO no longer trade in regulating power. The regulation as explained above, is based on a common list of bids and is activated in the country with the lowest prices. It is difficult to calculate ìnationalî market shares, since regulating power activated in one country might be used for regulation in another country. This implies at the same time, that prices are set on a transnational basis based on competitive bids.
58.The volume for secondary regulation comprising both upward and downward regulation amounted to 1.1 TWh in 2001-2002. Based on information from Svenska Kraftn‰t Sydkraft and Graninge had a combined market share of around [15 ñ 25]%. The other suppliers were Vattenfall, Fortum and SkellefteÂ.
59.Considering the large amount of regulating power originating from especially Norway, the partiesí combined market share considering a Nordic market for regulating power, will be significantly lower than in Sweden and will not give rise to competition concerns.
60.The partiesí combined market shares of around [20 ñ 30]% for primary regulation and around [15 ñ 25]% for secondary regulation only refers to regulating power originating in Sweden. Considering the large trade of regulating power between Sweden and its neighbouring countries, this transaction is not likely to create any competition concerns on the market for regulating power neither considering a market for primary regulation nor considering a market for secondary regulation.
- Finland
61.Every electricity producer in Finland has a balance responsibility; i.e. must balance its production and the consumption of its customers. Neither E.ON Finland nor Graninge are balance providers to the Finnish TSO Fingrid. It can be concluded that the proposed transaction will not have an effect on the regulating power market in Finland.
62.The proposed transaction will not create any competition concerns on the regulating power market in Finland and no significant competition concerns on either the market for primary regulation power or on the market for secondary regulation power in Sweden or in the Nordic area.
63.Variations in precipitation and temperature can result in large variations in the electricity spot price. This means that there is a high risk associated with electricity trading. To reduce this risk, market players can hedge their purchases and sales with a time horizon of up to four years. Nord Poolís derivatives market covers futures, forwards, options and contracts for difference (cdf) with the system price as the reference price. Essentially the financial market has to do with the trading of risk rather than with electricity as such.
64.Sydkraft believes that all financial products offered on the Nord Pool and the OTC market belong to the same market, since futures, forwards, options and clearing services are used for price hedging and risk management. According to Sydkraft, financial and physical trading of electricity belong to the same relevant market because all financial contracts are using the system price from the Nord Pool.
65.The market investigation has not confirmed this. The majority of the replies state that the physical and the financial electricity trading are separate markets although they are closely linked having the system price as a common reference price.
66.In previous decisions, the Commission has found that electricity trading is a product market separate from other electricity markets. For the purpose of this decision, the precise product market definition can be left open, since the proposed transaction will not lead to competition concerns in any event.
67.Sydkraft considers that the relevant scope of the financial market is at least Nordic, if not global, since the financial instruments do not require any electricity operations in the Nord Pool area. The results of the market investigation indicate that the geographic market should not be narrower than the Nord Pool area. For the purpose of this decision, it is however not necessary to define the exact scope of the geographic market, since the transaction does not strengthen or create a dominant position in either of the two proposed areas.
68.In 2002, the volume of financial contracts traded at the Nord Pool market was 1,019 TWh and the volume of OTC/bilateral financial contracts cleared at the Nord Pool was 2,089 TWh, in total 3,108 TWh.
69.In 2002, Sydkraft traded approximately [135 ñ 145] TWh and Graninge traded approximately [15 ñ 25] TWh corresponding to market shares of respectively [0 ñ 10]% and [0 ñ 10]% based on the total traded volume.
70.More than 250 participants from Norway, Sweden, Finland and Denmark as well as some from Great Britain, the Netherlands and USA trade on the financial Nord Pool market. All trading is anonymous and all trade with Nord Pool as counterpart.
71.Taking into consideration the limited volume of the partiesí combined trading activities the proposed transaction is not likely to affect the functioning of the financial markets.
72.In previous decisions, the Commission has found that transmission and distribution of electricity constitute separate markets. Transmission is carried out on different networks owned by different operators. No networks overlap. Both Sydkraft and Graninge own and operate transmission and distribution lines in Finland and Sweden. Access to the network is based on regulated third-party access obliging the operator to connect all customers who want to be connected to the network. The network authorities scrutinise network tariff and other terms on which network services are provided.
73.According to Sydkraft, transmission and distribution networks both constitute natural monopolies and thus no horizontal overlaps occur as a result of the transaction.
74.In the Nordic countries, the transmission and distribution of electricity is each usually regarded as a natural monopoly. The precise scope of the product market(s) can be left open, because the transaction does not give rise to competition concerns due to the regulated access to and control of the networks by the network authorities.
17See e.g. Commission decision of 25.7.2002 in case No M.2890 ñ EDF/Seeboard, recital 10 with further references.
18ìA Powerful Competition Policyî, (cf. footnote 6,), p. 30.
13
48.Balance regulation is carried out by way of primary regulation and secondary regulation. Primary regulation means that the physical balance in the system is adjusted by automatically increasing or decreasing of the production in a number of power plants. A Nordic agreement between the TSOs sets out the level of regulation effect to be held in store for primary regulation by each country. Svenska Kraftn‰t is to procure 2,400 MW/Hz out of the total demand of the Nordic system of 6,000 MW/Hz.
49.Secondary balance regulation is a manual adjustment upwards or downwards of regulation objects and is carried out through power trades with the balance providers that have signed agreements with Svenska Kraftn‰t to take part in the balance regulation. Secondary regulation is used when the primary regulation is not sufficient and is aimed at restoring the primary regulation whose task it is inter alia to be a reserve in case of sudden disruptions in the power system. Primary regulation is for the most part procured nationally yet its price follows the price for secondary regulation, which in turn is determined by bids from suppliers in all the Nordic countries.
50.Sydkraft considers the balance regulation market to form a part of the overall wholesale market. This is in line with a study by Copenhagen Economics. This argument is built on two main reasons. First, that supply substitution is feasible and likely to be swift, so that prices on one of the markets cannot rise significantly without generators quickly moving capacity from the other three markets (Elspot, Elbas and regulating power market). Secondly, that there may be some demand substitution between the bilateral market and the spot market.
51.The market investigation indicates that balance regulation may constitute a separate product market. However, for the purpose of this decision it can be left open whether balance regulation constitutes a separate product market as well as whether primary and secondary balance regulation constitute separate segments within this product market, since the proposed transaction will not create any competition concerns under either market definition.
52.The regulating power markets in the Nordic countries were combined in September 2002. The balance of the synchronous part of the Nordic electricity market is now controlled based on the frequency. Bids for regulating power in all the countries are compiled in a merit order list available to all Nordic TSOs in a common information system NOIS (Nordic Operational Information System). The TSOs in Norway and Sweden maintain the frequency by making common decisions to upward or downward regulate, by activating the bids from the common list. If the grid is congested the regulation necessary to alleviate the bottlenecks are made first, followed by regulation of the frequency. Bids are activated in the merit order to secure the lowest price possible for the regulating power.
14ìRelevant markets in the Nordic areaî, Copenhagen Economics, 21 October 2002. The report is available on www.nordel.org.
15ìCommon Balance Management in the Nordic Countriesî, special print of the feature article in Nordelís 2002 report.
53.Svenska Kraftn‰t procures around 2,400 MW/Hz of capacity for primary regulation. The procurement of the majority of this capacity is made from Swedish suppliers, for the reason that Svenska Kraftn‰t is responsible for the Swedish market. However, a part of the capacity for primary regulation in Sweden is supplied by Statnett Norge and Fingrid Finland.
54.Statistics from Svenska Kraftn‰t for the period September 2002ñAugust 2003 show that Norway was the largest provider of both upward and downward regulating power in the Nordic area. Norway accounted for around 50% of the total regulating power market in the Nordic area. This high figure is based on low regulating power prices based on cheap hydropower. By comparison, Swedenís share of the total Nordic regulation market was around 30%. It has not been possible to obtain information about the actual flow of regulating power between the Nordic countries. However, figures from Svenska Kraftn‰t show a considerable trade. In the period September 2002 - August 2003, Svenska Kraftn‰t sold regulating power for more than 176.9 MSEK and bought for around 358.5 MSEK.
55.For the purpose of this decision the precise scope of the geographic market can be left open, since the transaction will not lead to competition concerns on either a national or a Nordic basis.
- Sweden
56.Svenska Kraftn‰t estimates the Swedish part of the overall regulation market to be 1.346 MSEK and around 5.7 million MWh in 2002. These figures comprise both regulation power and balancing power. Regulating power is used to maintain the balance of the frequency of the total power system, whereas balancing power is used to cover the deviations between contracted and actual supply and demand of each player.
57.Svenska Kraftn‰t procures primary regulation in two phases of packages of 20MW/Hz. According to Sydkraft, Svenska Kraftn‰tís annual cost of primary regulation procurement has varied between 50-200 MSEK per year. According to information from Svenska Kraftn‰t Sydkraft and Graninge had a combined market share of around [20 ñ 30]% in 2002. Since September 2002 the TSO no longer trade in regulating power. The regulation as explained above, is based on a common list of bids and is activated in the country with the lowest prices. It is difficult to calculate ìnationalî market shares, since regulating power activated in one country might be used for regulation in another country. This implies at the same time, that prices are set on a transnational basis based on competitive bids.
58.The volume for secondary regulation comprising both upward and downward regulation amounted to 1.1 TWh in 2001-2002. Based on information from Svenska Kraftn‰t Sydkraft and Graninge had a combined market share of around [15 ñ 25]%. The other suppliers were Vattenfall, Fortum and SkellefteÂ.
59.Considering the large amount of regulating power originating from especially Norway, the partiesí combined market share considering a Nordic market for regulating power, will be significantly lower than in Sweden and will not give rise to competition concerns.
60.The partiesí combined market shares of around [20 ñ 30]% for primary regulation and around [15 ñ 25]% for secondary regulation only refers to regulating power originating in Sweden. Considering the large trade of regulating power between Sweden and its neighbouring countries, this transaction is not likely to create any competition concerns on the market for regulating power neither considering a market for primary regulation nor considering a market for secondary regulation.
- Finland
61.Every electricity producer in Finland has a balance responsibility; i.e. must balance its production and the consumption of its customers. Neither E.ON Finland nor Graninge are balance providers to the Finnish TSO Fingrid. It can be concluded that the proposed transaction will not have an effect on the regulating power market in Finland.
62.The proposed transaction will not create any competition concerns on the regulating power market in Finland and no significant competition concerns on either the market for primary regulation power or on the market for secondary regulation power in Sweden or in the Nordic area.
63.Variations in precipitation and temperature can result in large variations in the electricity spot price. This means that there is a high risk associated with electricity trading. To reduce this risk, market players can hedge their purchases and sales with a time horizon of up to four years. Nord Poolís derivatives market covers futures, forwards, options and contracts for difference (cdf) with the system price as the reference price. Essentially the financial market has to do with the trading of risk rather than with electricity as such.
64.Sydkraft believes that all financial products offered on the Nord Pool and the OTC market belong to the same market, since futures, forwards, options and clearing services are used for price hedging and risk management. According to Sydkraft, financial and physical trading of electricity belong to the same relevant market because all financial contracts are using the system price from the Nord Pool.
65.The market investigation has not confirmed this. The majority of the replies state that the physical and the financial electricity trading are separate markets although they are closely linked having the system price as a common reference price.
66.In previous decisions, the Commission has found that electricity trading is a product market separate from other electricity markets. For the purpose of this decision, the precise product market definition can be left open, since the proposed transaction will not lead to competition concerns in any event.
67.Sydkraft considers that the relevant scope of the financial market is at least Nordic, if not global, since the financial instruments do not require any electricity operations in the Nord Pool area. The results of the market investigation indicate that the geographic market should not be narrower than the Nord Pool area. For the purpose of this decision, it is however not necessary to define the exact scope of the geographic market, since the transaction does not strengthen or create a dominant position in either of the two proposed areas.
68.In 2002, the volume of financial contracts traded at the Nord Pool market was 1,019 TWh and the volume of OTC/bilateral financial contracts cleared at the Nord Pool was 2,089 TWh, in total 3,108 TWh.
69.In 2002, Sydkraft traded approximately [135 ñ 145] TWh and Graninge traded approximately [15 ñ 25] TWh corresponding to market shares of respectively [0 ñ 10]% and [0 ñ 10]% based on the total traded volume.
70.More than 250 participants from Norway, Sweden, Finland and Denmark as well as some from Great Britain, the Netherlands and USA trade on the financial Nord Pool market. All trading is anonymous and all trade with Nord Pool as counterpart.
71.Taking into consideration the limited volume of the partiesí combined trading activities the proposed transaction is not likely to affect the functioning of the financial markets.
72.In previous decisions, the Commission has found that transmission and distribution of electricity constitute separate markets. Transmission is carried out on different networks owned by different operators. No networks overlap. Both Sydkraft and Graninge own and operate transmission and distribution lines in Finland and Sweden. Access to the network is based on regulated third-party access obliging the operator to connect all customers who want to be connected to the network. The network authorities scrutinise network tariff and other terms on which network services are provided.