EUR-Lex & EU Commission AI-Powered Semantic Search Engine
Modern Legal
  • Query in any language with multilingual search
  • Access EUR-Lex and EU Commission case law
  • See relevant paragraphs highlighted instantly
Start free trial

Similar Documents

Explore similar documents to your case.

We Found Similar Cases for You

Sign up for free to view them and see the most relevant paragraphs highlighted.

Opinion of Advocate General Rantos delivered on 9 December 2021.#Servizio Elettrico Nazionale SpA and Others v Autorità Garante della Concorrenza e del Mercato and Others.#Request for a preliminary ruling from the Consiglio di Stato.#Reference for a preliminary ruling – Competition – Dominant position – Abuse – Article 102 TFEU – Effect of a practice on the well-being of consumers and on the structure of the market – Abusive exclusionary practice – Whether the practice is capable of producing an exclusionary effect – Use of means other than those coming within the scope of competition on the merits – Hypothetical as-efficient competitor unable to replicate the practice – Existence of an anticompetitive intent – Opening up of the market for the sale of electricity to competition – Transfer of commercially sensitive information within a group of undertakings in order to preserve a dominant position inherited from a statutory monopoly – Imputability of a subsidiary’s conduct to the parent company.#Case C-377/20.

ECLI:EU:C:2021:998

62020CC0377

December 9, 2021
With Google you find a lot.
With us you find everything. Try it now!

I imagine what I want to write in my case, I write it in the search engine and I get exactly what I wanted. Thank you!

Valentina R., lawyer

delivered on 9 December 2021 (1)

Case C‑377/20

Servizio Elettrico Nazionale SpA,

ENEL SpA,

Enel Energia SpA

and interveners

Eni Gas e Luce SpA,

Eni SpA,

Axpo Italia SpA,

Gala SpA,

Green Network SpA,

Associazione Italiana di Grossisti di Energia e Trader – AIGET,

Ass.ne Codici – Centro per i Diritti del Cittadino,

Associazione Energia Libera,

Metaenergia SpA

(Request for a preliminary ruling from the Consiglio di Stato (Council of State, Italy))

(Reference for a preliminary ruling – Competition – Dominant position – Abuse – Article 102 TFEU – Opening up of the market for the sale of electricity to competition – Use of commercially sensitive information within a dominant group of undertakings – Imputability of the subsidiary’s conduct to the parent company)

1.This request for a preliminary ruling raises a considerable number of questions concerning the interpretation and application of Article 102 TFEU in connection with exclusionary conduct of dominant undertakings.

2.In the present case, the conduct at issue in the main proceedings, investigated by the Autorità Garante della Concorrenza e del Mercato (‘the AGCM’), (2) took place against the backdrop of the opening up of the market for the supply of electricity in Italy and took the form of an alleged complex abusive strategy implemented by the three companies of the ENEL SpA Group (the incumbent operator) seeking, in essence, to make it more difficult for competitors to enter the liberalised market. More specifically, that strategy allegedly consisted in the discriminatory use of data relating to customers of the protected market which, prior to the liberalisation, were available to Servizio Elettrico Nazionale SpA (‘SEN’), one of the companies of the Enel Group, in its capacity as the market operator. The objective pursued was allegedly to use those data to issue commercial offers to the customers of that market in order to transfer those customers within the Enel Group, namely from SEN to the subsidiary of the group active on the free market, namely Enel Energia SpA (‘EE’). That was allegedly to prevent the large-scale departure of SEN customers to third-party suppliers, in view of the abolition of that protected market.

3.It is against that background that the referring court asks the Court to clarify certain aspects of the concept of ‘abuse’ within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU, namely:

the constituent elements of abusive conduct, allowing a clear line to be drawn between practices which come within the scope of so-called ‘normal’ competition, on the one hand, and those which come within the scope of distorted competition, on the other;

more philosophically, the interests protected by Article 102 TFEU, for the purpose of ascertaining the evidence that must be taken into consideration when assessing whether there is abusive conduct;

the admissibility and the relevance of evidence submitted ex post by the dominant undertakings demonstrating the absence of actual effects of allegedly abusive conduct in order to contest the capacity of that conduct to have restrictive effects on competition; and

the relevance of the intention to restrict competition in the assessment of the abusive nature of particular conduct.

4.Although the existing case-law provides some points of reference for usefully answering those questions, the present case has particular features which make it of particular interest.

5.First of all, the conduct at issue in the main proceedings is, correctly, described by the referring court as ‘atypical’, in that it does not correspond to the examples of conduct listed in Article 102 TFEU and is not a type of conduct which is systematically analysed in national decision-making practices or decision-making practices of the European Commission. In that regard, I note that the EU Courts have had the opportunity to apply Article 102 TFEU in the context of liberalised markets for the purpose of ensuring equal access for new undertakings on the liberalised market. However, those cases mostly concerned conduct constituting price-related exclusionary conduct implemented by the incumbent operator in the context of cases relating to network industries. (3) Accordingly, the present case gives the Court the opportunity to address a wider issue regarding the application of Article 102 TFEU to liberalised markets, namely when the abusive conduct is based on the competitive advantage that an incumbent operator lawfully ‘inherited’ from its former statutory monopoly, such as the brand image and reputation or the customer base. (4)

6.Next, the present case will allow the Court to confirm its recent case-law arising from the judgments in TeliaSonera, (5) Post Danmark I and II, (6) Intel, (7) Generics (UK) (8) and Deutsche Telekom II, in which the Court showed itself to be open to a less formal approach to the assessment of the abusive nature of particular conduct, based on an examination of the effects and taking account of both the legal characteristics of the conduct in question and its economic context. More specifically, this case gives the Court the opportunity to clarify whether certain principles arising from that recent case-law relating to price-related exclusionary conduct and, in particular, the ‘equally efficient competitor’ test, can be said to apply in the context of exclusionary conduct not related to pricing, such as that at issue in the main proceedings.

7.Lastly, the present case is of particular interest in that it concerns a type of conduct relating to the abusive use of databases, which is now a very significant indicator of strength on certain markets, even beyond the context of the digital economy. The guidance provided may therefore prove to be useful in the future for assessing, under Article 102 TFEU, conduct relating to the use of data.

II. The dispute in the main proceedings, the questions referred for a preliminary ruling and the procedure before the Court

8.The present case arose in the context of the gradual liberalisation of the market for the retail supply of electricity in Italy.

9.In an initial phase of the opening up of the market, a distinction was drawn between, on the one hand, customers that were so-called ‘eligible’ to choose a supplier on the free market other than their territorially competent distributor and, on the other, so-called ‘captive’ customers, comprising private individuals and small businesses that, being regarded as incapable of negotiating energy supply contracts in full awareness of the facts or from a position of strength, benefited from a regulated regime referred to as the ‘Servizio di maggior tutela’ (Enhanced protection service) – that is to say a protected market under the supervision of a national sectoral regulatory authority in so far as concerned the definition of the conditions of sale.

10.In a subsequent phase, the ‘captive’ customers too were gradually allowed access to the free market. The Italian legislature provided for the final step in the transition from the regulated market to the free market – in which the captive customers would be able to choose freely whichever offer they considered best suited to their needs, without any protection – by setting the date from which special price protection would no longer be available. After a number of postponements, the transition date was set at 1 January 2021 for small and medium-sized undertakings and 1 January 2022 for householders.

11.It is in that context that Enel, a vertically integrated undertaking holding the monopoly in electricity generation in Italy and also active in the distribution of electricity, underwent an unbundling process, so as to guarantee transparent and non-discriminatory conditions of access to essential production and distribution infrastructure. As a result of that process, the various stages of the distribution process were assigned to separate undertakings, namely E-Distribuzione, the concession holder for the distribution service, EE, a supplier of electricity on the free market, and SEN, the operator, inter alia, of the ‘enhanced protection service’, of which E-Distribuzione is the concession holder for the distribution service.

12.The present dispute arose from a complaint lodged with the AGCM by the Associazione Italiana di Grossisti di Energia e Trader (the Italian association of energy wholesalers and traders; ‘AIGET’) and from information received from individual customers complaining of the unlawful use of commercially sensitive information by operators having access to that information as a result of their belonging to the Enel Group. It was for that reason that, on 4 May 2017, the AGCM opened an investigation into Enel, SEN, and EE in order to establish whether the combined conduct of those companies constituted an infringement of Article 102 TFEU.

13.That investigation concluded with the adoption of a decision on 20 December 2018 (‘the contested decision’), in which the AGCM held that, during the period from January 2012 to May 2017, SEN and EE, coordinated by their parent company, Enel, had abused their dominant position, in breach of Article 102 TFEU, on the markets for the sale of electricity to domestic and non-domestic users connected to the low-voltage grid in the areas where the Enel Group managed the distribution activity (‘the market in question’). Consequently, the AGCM imposed a fine of EUR 93084 790.50 jointly and severally on those three companies.

14.The conduct complained of consisted in the implementation of an exclusionary strategy on the market in question, designed to ‘transfer’ SEN’s customer base (SEN being the operator on the protected market) to EE (active on the free market). The objective of the Enel Group had allegedly been, in particular, to prevent the large-scale departure of SEN customers to third-party suppliers, in view of the (forthcoming) abolition of the protected market, which, according to the procedures discussed in draft legislation from 2015 onwards, could entail the reallocation of these customers by means of ‘auctions’.

15.To that end, according to the AGCM, SEN had, in the first place, obtained the consent of its customers in the protected market to receive commercial offers in the free market using ‘discriminatory methods’, consisting in requesting that consent, separately, for the companies of the Enel Group, on the one hand, and for third parties, on the other. In this way, the customers approached tended to give their consent for the companies of the Enel Group, believing that to do so was necessary for, or appropriate to, the management of their contract with their supplier, and refused their consent for other operators. SEN thus placed a quantitative limit on the amount of personal data available to EE’s competitors on the free market, since the number of responses giving consent to receive commercial offers also from competing operators represented just 30% of the total number of responses giving consent. The names of the customers of the protected market who consented to receiving commercial offers were entered on special lists (‘the SEN lists’).

16.In the second place, that exclusionary strategy was put into effect by means of EE’s use of the SEN lists to issue commercial offers to the protected customers (namely, the ‘Sempre con Te’ offer), with a view to bringing those customers across from the protected market to the free market. Accordingly, Enel transferred the SEN lists to its subsidiary EE, through the intermediary of SEN, on terms that were not available to competitors. According to the AGCM, the SEN lists were a ‘strategic, non-replicable asset’, thanks to the otherwise unavailable information they contained concerning users’ subscription to the ‘Enhanced protection service’, which enabled EE to target offers exclusively at that category of customer. In addition, the use of the SEN lists had had a ‘potential restrictive effect’, inasmuch as it had enabled EE to take from its competitors a significant proportion (more than 40%) of the ‘contestable demand’ of customers moving from the protected market to the free market.

17.The companies of the Enel Group brought separate actions challenging the contested decision before the Tribunale amministrativo regionale per il Lazio (Regional Administrative Court, Lazio, Italy), the court of first instance.

18.By judgments of 17 October 2019, that court, while finding that there had been an abuse of a dominant position, partially upheld the actions brought by EE and SEN, in so far as concerned the duration of the alleged abuse and the criteria used to calculate the fine. In compliance with those judgments, the AGCM reduced the fine to EUR 27 529 786.46. By contrast, the court of first instance dismissed the action brought by Enel in its entirety and also confirmed the fine imposed.

19.The three companies have brought separate appeals against those judgments before the referring court, the Consiglio di Stato (Council of State, Italy), seeking the annulment of the decisions imposing the fines or, in the alternative, a further reduction in the fine.

20.In support of their appeals, the appellants argued, in the first place, that there is no evidence of the abusive nature of their conduct or, in particular, of the capacity (potential) of that conduct to have anticompetitive exclusionary effects.

21.First of all, they consider that the mere inclusion of a customer’s name on a telemarketing list for the purpose of promoting the services of a subsidiary is not abusive conduct, since it does not entail any commitment regarding supply and does not prevent the customer from appearing on other lists, from receiving advertising or from changing supplier at any moment, even repeatedly.

22.Next, according to the appellants, using the SEN lists was not likely to bring about the rapid transfer of customers en masse from SEN to EE. Indeed, between March and May 2017, the two months between the launch of the ‘Sempre con Te’ offer and the closure of telephone sales, EE managed to obtain, using the SEN lists, only 478 customers, representing 0.002% of the users of the ‘Enhanced protection service’ and 0.001% of all electricity users. In addition, the AGCM failed to examine the economic evidence provided by the appellants, which showed that the conduct in question was not liable to produce, and did not produce, restrictive effects on competition. In that regard, the positive results achieved by EE in winning ‘Enhanced protection service’ customers were due to two perfectly legitimate factors which offer an alternative, more convincing explanation than that put forward by the AGCM: first, the fact that performance on the free market was better for companies within the Enel Group, which include the distribution undertaking having territorial competence, and, second, the attractive nature of the Enel brand.

Lastly, the SEN lists were neither strategic nor non-replicable, since there were similar lists of ‘Enhanced protection service’ customers available on the market that were more complete and less costly.

In the second place, Enel challenged the AGCM’s application of a prima facie presumption of parent company liability. It argues in this connection that, from 2014, a major reorganisation of the Enel Group was undertaken, at the conclusion of which decision-making processes were decentralised. Within the new organisational structure the parent company merely had the function of promoting synergies and best practices among the various operating companies, having left behind its decision-making role.

According to the referring court, which has joined the three appeals, there is no doubt that the Enel Group holds a dominant position on the market in question. However, the concept of ‘abuse’, in particular in so far as concerns ‘atypical’ abuse, such as that at issue in the case in the main proceedings aimed at preventing growth in, or the diversification of, competitors’ offers, raises problems of interpretation, in that, on the one hand, Article 102 TFEU does not set out exhaustive parameters for definition and, on the other hand, the traditional distinction between exploitative abuses and exclusionary abuses is not relevant.

Indeed, for the purpose of establishing an abuse of a dominant position, the referring court wishes to know, amongst other things, the extent to which account should be taken of the strategy of the Enel Group, as it appears from the documents gathered by the AGCM, to prevent the departure of SEN customers to competitors, or of the fact that the conduct of the group was in itself legitimate, in the sense that the SEN lists were obtained lawfully. The referring court also questions whether it is sufficient that the conduct in question is capable of excluding competitors from the relevant market, given that the group produced, during the course of the investigation, economic studies seeking to demonstrate that its conduct had not actually had any exclusionary effects. Lastly, the abuse of a dominant position by a group of undertakings raises the question of whether it is necessary to adduce proof of active coordination among the various companies operating within the group, or whether the mere fact of belonging to the group is sufficient to establish that a contribution has been made to the abusive practice, even by an undertaking in the group that has not engaged in the abusive conduct.

Against that background, being uncertain as to the correct interpretation to be given to Article 102 TFEU, the Consiglio di Stato (Council of State) decided to stay the proceedings and refer the following five questions to the Court of Justice for a preliminary ruling:

(1)‘(1) May conduct that constitutes an abuse of a dominant position be completely lawful in and of itself and be classified as “an abuse” solely because of the (potentially) restrictive effect created in the reference market, or must that conduct also be characterised by a specific “unlawful” component, represented by the use of “competitive methods (or means) that are different” from those that are “normal”? In the latter case, what criteria should be used to establish the boundary between “normal” and “distorted” competition?

(2)Is the purpose of the concept of abuse to maximise the well-being of consumers, with the court being responsible for determining whether that well-being has been (or could be) reduced, or does the concept of an infringement of competition law have the function of preserving in itself the competitive structure of the market, in order to avoid the creation of economic power groupings that are, in any case, considered harmful for the community?

(3)In the case of an abuse of a dominant position represented by an attempt to prevent the continuation or development of the existing level of competition, is the dominant undertaking in any case permitted to prove that the conduct did not cause any actual harm, despite its abstract ability to generate a restrictive effect? If the answer to that question is in the affirmative, for the purposes of assessing whether an atypical exclusionary abuse has occurred, must Article 102 TFEU be interpreted as meaning that the Authority has an obligation to examine specifically the economic analyses produced by the party concerning the actual ability of the conduct examined to exclude its competitors from the market?

(4)Must an abuse of a dominant position be assessed solely in terms of its effects on the market (including merely potential effects), without regard to the subjective motive of the [operator], or does a demonstration of restrictive intent constitute a parameter that may be used (even exclusively) to assess the abusive nature of the dominant undertaking’s conduct? Does such a demonstration of the subjective component serve only to shift the burden of proof to the dominant undertaking (which would have the burden, at this stage, of providing evidence that the exclusionary effect is absent)?

(5)In the case of a dominant position held by a number of undertakings belonging to the same corporate group, is being part of that group sufficient reason to assume that even those undertakings that have not implemented the abusive conduct have contributed to the infringement, so that [the competition authority] would merely need to demonstrate a conscious, albeit non-collusive, parallel approach by the undertakings operating within the collectively dominant group? Or (as is the case for the prohibition on cartels) is there in any case a need to provide evidence, even indirect evidence, of a specific situation of coordination and instrumentality among the various undertakings within the dominant group, in particular in order to demonstrate the involvement of the parent company?’

Written observations have been submitted to the Court by SEN, EE and Enel, the appellants in the main proceedings, by the AGCM, the respondent in those proceedings, by AIGET and Green Network SpA., interveners in the main proceedings, by the Italian and Norwegian Governments and by the European Commission. In their observations, SEN, EE and the Norwegian Government have focused on the first to fourth questions and Enel has addressed the fifth question alone.

With the exception of Enel, all of those parties also made oral submissions at the hearing on 9 September 2021. The German Government and the European Free Trade Association (EFTA) Surveillance Authority, which had not lodged written submissions, also presented argument at the hearing.

III. Analysis

By the first question it has submitted for a preliminary ruling, the referring court asks whether a practice that is considered ‘perfectly legal’ outside the context of competition law, and that is implemented by an undertaking in a dominant position, may be classified as an ‘abuse’, within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU, solely because of its (potentially) restrictive effect, or whether that conduct must also be characterised by a specific element of ‘objective unlawfulness’, consisting in the use of methods different from methods of ‘normal’ competition. In the latter case, the Court is asked to indicate the criteria according to which a line may be drawn between ‘normal’ competition and ‘distorted’ competition. (9)

This preliminary question in reality comprises four parts which are intrinsically linked but which, for simplicity, I shall address separately in the order in which they are raised:

the first part seeks to establish the relevance of the lawfulness of particular conduct under branches of law other than competition law to its characterisation as an abuse within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU;

the second part seeks to establish whether particular conduct may be classified as an abuse merely because it produces potentially restrictive effects;

the third part seeks to establish whether, in order to be classified as an abuse, the conduct must also be characterised by an additional element of unlawfulness, namely the use of competitive methods or means other than those of ‘normal competition’, and

the fourth part seeks to distinguish practices which constitute abuse within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU, in that they entail the use of competitive means other than those of normal competition, from practices which do not give rise to abuse.

By the first part, the referring court asks whether, for the purposes of Article 102 TFEU, an abuse of a dominant position may be found in respect of conduct which is lawful under branches of law other than competition law.

This question is based on the referring court’s finding that the methods used to obtain consent for inclusion on the SEN lists were unquestionably lawful under civil law, inasmuch as no complaint has been lodged alleging infringement of the specific rules governing the processing of personal data and EE had acquired the SEN lists at the market price.

It should be noted at the outset that it has been consistently held that the concept of ‘abuse’ within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU is an ‘objective concept relating to the conduct of a dominant undertaking which, on a market where the degree of competition is already weakened precisely because of the presence of the undertaking concerned, through recourse to methods different from those governing normal competition in products or services on the basis of the transactions of commercial operators, has the effect of hindering the maintenance of the degree of competition still existing in the market or the growth of that competition’. (10)

It follows that the concept of ‘abuse’ is founded on the objective assessment of the capacity of particular conduct to restrict competition, without the legal classification of that conduct under other branches of the law being decisive.

Accordingly, the Court has held that ‘the illegality of abusive conduct under [Article 102 TFEU] is unrelated to its compliance or non-compliance with other legal rules and, in the majority of cases, abuses of dominant positions consist of behaviour which is otherwise lawful under branches of law other than competition law. (11)

Indeed, if only practices which objectively restrict competition and are at the same time unlawful were regarded as abusive within the meaning of that provision, that would mean that conduct which is potentially harmful to competition could not, merely because it is lawful, be penalised under Article 102 TFEU. Such a result would mean that it might almost never be possible to establish abuse of a dominant position, which would compromise the objective of that provision – that being to establish a system which ensures that competition in the internal market is not distorted. Conversely, conduct which infringes legal rules in a given sector is not necessarily an abuse on the part of the dominant undertaking when it is not liable to cause harm, even potential harm, to competition. (12)

It follows that, in the present case, the fact that consent for the SEN lists was lawfully acquired under the rules of civil law cannot preclude the conduct from being classified as abusive within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU. However, it is for the referring court to examine whether, in the light, inter alia, of the regulatory framework governing the processing of personal data, the methods of obtaining the consent could be ‘discriminatory’, as the AGCM contends. (13) In that regard, the specific legal framework applicable (and conformity with it) may constitute a relevant factor during the overall assessment of the abusive nature of the conduct. (14)

By the second part, the referring court asks whether particular conduct may be classified as abusive merely because of the (potentially) restrictive effects it has on the relevant market.

In this connection I would reiterate that the concept of ‘abuse’, described above, implies that the conduct penalised by Article 102 TFEU is conduct which hinders the maintenance of the degree of competition on the market or the growth of that competition. (15) Indeed, it is settled case-law that undertakings holding a dominant position have, pursuant to Article 102 TFEU, a special responsibility not to allow their conduct to impair genuine undistorted competition in the internal market. (16)

More specifically, as regards exclusionary practices, such as that at issue in the case in the main proceedings, (17) the Court has held repeatedly, first, that if conduct is to be characterised as abusive, that presupposes that it was capable of restricting competition and, in particular, of producing the alleged exclusionary effects, (18) that assessment having to be undertaken with regard to all the relevant facts surrounding the conduct in question. (19) Second, in order to establish whether such a practice is abusive, that practice must have an anticompetitive effect on the market which is not purely hypothetical, (20) and thus must exist, but the effect does not necessarily have to be concrete, and it is sufficient to demonstrate that there is an anticompetitive effect which may potentially exclude competitors that are at least as efficient as the dominant undertaking. (21)

It follows that the capacity to produce a (potentially) restrictive effect on the relevant market, such as an anticompetitive exclusionary (or foreclosure) effect, is the essential factor in the characterisation of conduct as abusive.

However, in this connection, it must be emphasised that an exclusionary effect does not necessarily undermine competition and does not, therefore, always equate to a ‘restrictive effect in the reference market’ (to follow the wording of the question). Indeed, the mere fact that certain conduct has the potential to drive a competitor from the market does not make the market less competitive, still less does it make the conduct abusive within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU. A distinction must therefore be drawn between a risk of foreclosure and a risk of anticompetitive foreclosure, since only the latter may be penalised under Article 102 TFEU. (22)

Indeed, as the Court explained in the judgment in Intel, ‘it is in no way the purpose of Article 102 TFEU to prevent an undertaking from acquiring, on its own merits, the dominant position on a market. Nor does that provision seek to ensure that competitors less efficient than the undertaking with the dominant position should remain on the market. … Thus, not every exclusionary effect is necessarily detrimental to competition. Competition on the merits may, by definition, lead to the departure from the market or the marginalisation of competitors that are less efficient and so less attractive to consumers from the point of view of, among other things, price, choice, quality or innovation.’ (23) Accordingly, an undertaking remains at liberty to demonstrate that its practice, albeit producing an exclusionary effect, is objectively (economically) justified on the basis of all the circumstances of the case (24) or that the effects are counterbalanced, or outweighed, by advantages in terms of efficiency which also benefit the consumer. (25) That balancing of the favourable and unfavourable effects of the practice in question on competition can be carried out only after an analysis of the intrinsic capacity of that practice to foreclose competitors which are at least as efficient as the dominant undertaking. (26)

The premiss upon which the Court based that reasoning is therefore that if any conduct having an exclusionary effect (actual or potential) were automatically classed as anticompetitive and, therefore, abusive within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU, that provision would become a means for protecting less capable, less efficient undertakings and would in no way protect the more meritorious undertakings, which can serve as a stimulus to a market’s competitiveness.

In light of the foregoing analysis, in order for conduct, such as an exclusionary practice, to be classified as abusive within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU, it is necessary for it to be anticompetitive with the result that it is capable of having an (actual or potential) restrictive effect on the reference market. However, in order to assess the anticompetitive nature of that conduct it is necessary to establish whether the dominant undertaking used methods other than those of ‘normal’ competition. It is precisely that assessment that is the subject of the third and fourth parts.

By the third part, the referring court asks a question regarding methodology, namely whether the need to show that a dominant undertaking has used methods other than those coming within the scope of ‘normal’ competition refers to an ‘additional element of unlawfulness’ over and above the requirement to demonstrate an anticompetitive exclusionary effect, such that ‘the capacity to restrict competition’ and ‘the use of means other than those of normal competition’ are separate conditions to be fulfilled in order for abuse to be established.

I would note in this regard that the positions of the parties in the main proceedings, of the governments and of the Commission diverge. (27) To my mind, demonstrating that a dominant undertaking used means other than those which come within the scope of ‘normal’ competition is not a requirement that needs to be assessed separately from the restrictive effect of the conduct.

Indeed, as is clear from point 44 of this Opinion, the analysis of the undertaking’s conduct plays a decisive role in the classification of its effects as anticompetitive. Thus, those two elements must be addressed in one and the same analysis. More specifically, in order to assess whether the exclusionary effect is (actually or potentially) restrictive of competition, it is necessary also to examine whether the means used come within the scope of ‘normal’ competition. Similarly, in order to determine whether the means used come within the scope of such competition, it is necessary to know whether the practices have the ability to foreclose, which is to say to cause (actual or potential) exclusionary effects in the market. Indeed, the classification of conduct as ‘anticompetitive’ cannot be part of a separate examination of the effects of that conduct. The two requirements are thus inextricably linked and must be assessed having regard to all the relevant facts surrounding the conduct in question. (28)

It may be concluded from this that the ability of a practice to produce an anticompetitive effect, on the one hand, and the use of means that do not come within the scope of normal competition, on the other, are conditions that come under the same assessment, aimed at determining whether that practice is abusive.

In the present case, it is apparent from the facts contained in the order for reference that the AGCM is of the view that the conduct of the Enel Group at issue had a restrictive effect on competition, in that the strategy implemented by the appellants sought, in essence, to prevent or make more difficult the entry of EE’s competitors into the free market. In the light of the foregoing analysis, it is for the referring court to verify whether the conduct allegedly putting into effect that strategy was capable, at least potentially, of having exclusionary effects on EE’s competitors and to assess whether that exclusionary effect was capable of adversely affecting competition, by establishing whether or not that conduct comes within the scope of ‘normal’ competition.

By the fourth part, the referring court asks the Court, in essence, to draw a clear line between practices which come within the scope of so-called ‘normal’ competition and those which do not. This question thus goes to the heart of what constitutes abuse within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU, and seeks to determine whether the conduct at issue in the main proceedings constitutes such abuse.

As a preliminary point, it should be observed that, where the national court refers to ‘normal competition’, it is using terminology repeatedly used by the Court. (29) I would note that the same meaning should be ascribed to the adjective ‘normal’ as is ascribed to the other expressions used to describe such competition, which include ‘fair competition’, (30)‘competition on the merits’ (31) and ‘competition on the basis of quality’. (32) I propose to use the expression ‘competition on the merits’ from this point onwards. (33) This plethora of expressions is indicative of the objective difficulty of establishing what constitutes abusive conduct. Indeed, formulating rules which allow conduct that is harmful to competition, and therefore abusive, to be clearly distinguished is neither easy nor intuitive. That complexity is linked, inevitably, to the objective difficulty of distinguishing in advance conduct which reveals aggressive, but lawful competitiveness from anticompetitive conduct. (34)

No doubt conscious of that difficulty, the EU legislature included in Article 102 TFEU an indicative list of abusive practices which does not exhaust all the methods of abusing a dominant position prohibited by EU law, (35) thus allowing the application of that provision to be adapted to different commercial practices over time. Therefore, a practice described by the referring court as ‘atypical’, such as that at issue in the main proceedings, which does not correspond to a practice listed in Article 102 TFEU, is also capable of constituting an abusive practice. Since the analysis is based on the anticompetitive effects and not the form of the conduct, a competition authority has to conduct careful verification of all the relevant facts, without making the slightest presumption, (36) since whether the conduct is ‘typical’ or ‘atypical’ is not decisive.

The concept of ‘competition on the merits’ is therefore abstract, since it does not correspond to a specific form of practices and cannot be defined in such a way as to make it possible to determine in advance whether or not particular conduct comes within the scope of such competition. Indeed, the Court has excluded the idea of an ‘abuse in itself’ (or an abuse per se), which is to say the existence of a practice that is inherently abusive, independently of any anticompetitive effect it may have. (37) The concept of ‘competition on the merits’ thus expresses an economic ideal the background to which is the current trend in EU competition law to favour an analysis of the anticompetitive effects of the conduct (‘effects-based approach’) rather than an analysis based on its form (‘form-based approach’). (38)

It follows that the question as to whether an exclusionary practice is a means consistent with competition on the merits is closely linked to the factual, legal and economic context of that practice. Indeed, the material scope of the dominant undertaking’s special responsibility must be considered in the light of the specific circumstances of each case. (39)

Despite the abstract nature of the concept of ‘competition on the merits’, some common elements may be gleaned from the case-law of the Court. Without prejudice to the assessment of the conduct at issue in the main proceedings, which it is for the referring court to perform, I believe that the following considerations could be useful.

In the first place, I note that ‘competition on the merits’ must be interpreted in close correlation with the equally settled principle of the case-law of the Court that an undertaking in a dominant position has a ‘special responsibility’ not to allow its conduct to impair genuine undistorted competition in the internal market. (40) However, that ‘special responsibility’ cannot deprive an undertaking in a dominant position of its right to take account of its own commercial interests. (41) To that effect, the reference to ‘methods other than those which come within the scope of competition on the merits’ serves to clarify the content of that ‘special responsibility’ incumbent on a dominant undertaking and to define the scope of action that is permitted.

The logical consequence of this ‘special responsibility’ is that conduct that is acceptable when adopted by an undertaking not in a dominant position could be characterised as abusive when adopted by an undertaking in a dominant position, on account of the effect that that conduct has on the relevant market. Indeed, a practice that is generally followed or business conduct which normally contributes to an improvement in the production or distribution of goods and which has a beneficial effect on competition may restrict such competition where it is engaged in by a dominant undertaking. (42)

In that regard, in the present case, I note that the ‘special responsibility’ applies to all dominant undertakings – including incumbent operators that previously held a monopoly, such as Enel, and operators with a public service obligation, such as SEN. As the Court has stated, ‘a finding that an undertaking has a dominant position is not in itself a recrimination but simply means that, irrespective of the reasons for which it has such a dominant position, the undertaking concerned has a special responsibility not to allow its conduct to impair genuine undistorted competition on the common market.’ (43) Accordingly, in the context of the liberalisation of the market, the Enel Group is subject to Article 102 TFEU and, in particular, the ‘special responsibility’, just as all other undertakings.

In the second place, as is apparent from point 55 of this Opinion, the form or type of conduct that is adopted by a dominant undertaking is not decisive in itself. What matters is whether the conduct tends to restrict competition or is capable of having that effect. (44) However, if conduct clearly departs from normal market practice, that may be considered a relevant factor to be taken into account in the assessment of whether there is abuse (in the same way as, for example, proof of intention). (45)

In the third place, and without claiming to be exhaustive, I note that conduct that does not come within the concept of ‘competition on the merits’ is generally characterised by the fact that it is not based on obvious economic reasons (46) or objective reasons. (47) Examples of competition on the merits, therefore, would include conduct which reduces the costs of the dominant undertaking by increasing efficiency in some way and which has the effect of broadening consumer choice by putting new goods on the market or by increasing the quantity or quality of the goods already on offer. By contrast, if there is no justification for the conduct other than to harm competitors, that conduct will necessarily not come within the scope of competition on the merits. (48)

In the fourth place, I note that ‘competition on the merits’, in the context of the application of Article 102 TFEU to exclusionary practices, refers, generally, to a competitive situation in which consumers benefit from lower prices, better quality and a wider choice of new or improved goods and services. (49)

In the present case, the very purpose of the liberalisation of the energy market is to open that market to competition precisely in order to achieve for consumers the beneficial effects of the competitive process, whether in relation to price, quality or choice of the services offered. Accordingly, in the context of such a process, the actions of the incumbent operator must not be of a nature to prevent or make more difficult the entry into the liberalised market of competitors, which must be able to operate on the free market on an equal footing. Indeed, the Court has stated that a system of undistorted competition can be guaranteed only if equality of opportunity is secured as between the various economic operators. (50)

Against that background, the question arises as to whether the Enel Group, which had the monopoly on the customers of the protected market, may legitimately wish to keep those customers within the group, despite the process of liberalisation of that market. It seems to me that that question should be answered in the affirmative.

Indeed, as has been noted in point 44 of this Opinion, Article 102 TFEU in no way aims to prevent an undertaking from achieving or maintaining, on its own merits, the dominant position on a market. It follows that even incumbent operators, from the moment they are subject to free competition, should seek to maximise their profits inter alia by means of retaining their customer base. Indeed, winning customers is an essential element of normal competition. Thus, the Enel Group is surely fully allowed, even expected, to implement practices that seek to improve its goods and services in order, inter alia, to remain competitive and retain its customer base. It therefore seems to me to be entirely in accordance with normal competition that a dominant undertaking, such as Enel, should wish to retain its customer base, even in the context of liberalisation. Accordingly, the implementation of a ‘strategy’ to retain customers cannot, in itself, constitute an abuse within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU.

Indeed, as has been noted in point 44 of this Opinion, Article 102 TFEU in no way aims to prevent an undertaking from achieving or maintaining, on its own merits, the dominant position on a market. It follows that even incumbent operators, from the moment they are subject to free competition, should seek to maximise their profits inter alia by means of retaining their customer base. Indeed, winning customers is an essential element of normal competition. Thus, the Enel Group is surely fully allowed, even expected, to implement practices that seek to improve its goods and services in order, inter alia, to remain competitive and retain its customer base. It therefore seems to me to be entirely in accordance with normal competition that a dominant undertaking, such as Enel, should wish to retain its customer base, even in the context of liberalisation. Accordingly, the implementation of a ‘strategy’ to retain customers cannot, in itself, constitute an abuse within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU.

In that respect, it seems to me that data collection in the context of the customer relationship remains, in principle, an entirely ‘normal’ operation in a standard competitive process. However, in the context of such an operation, precisely on account of the fact that it is dominant, Enel has a ‘special responsibility’ to adopt practices of competition on the merits which do not lead to compartmentalisation of the market. Thus, Enel must not adopt practices which, by exploiting the advantages stemming from the statutory monopoly, are capable of having exclusionary effects on new competitors considered to be as efficient as it is itself. (51)

In that respect, it seems to me that data collection in the context of the customer relationship remains, in principle, an entirely ‘normal’ operation in a standard competitive process. However, in the context of such an operation, precisely on account of the fact that it is dominant, Enel has a ‘special responsibility’ to adopt practices of competition on the merits which do not lead to compartmentalisation of the market. Thus, Enel must not adopt practices which, by exploiting the advantages stemming from the statutory monopoly, are capable of having exclusionary effects on new competitors considered to be as efficient as it is itself. (51)

It is in this connection that it is necessary, in my view, to assess, in the fifth place, the ability of competitors to imitate the conduct of the dominant undertaking. This assessment is relevant in order to determine whether the practice at issue comes within the scope of competition on the merits and, accordingly, whether or not it restricts competition.

It is in this connection that it is necessary, in my view, to assess, in the fifth place, the ability of competitors to imitate the conduct of the dominant undertaking. This assessment is relevant in order to determine whether the practice at issue comes within the scope of competition on the merits and, accordingly, whether or not it restricts competition.

Indeed, the case-law of the Court, in my view, confirms that exclusionary conduct of a dominant undertaking which can be replicated by equally efficient competitors does not represent, in principle, conduct that may lead to anticompetitive foreclosure and therefore comes within the scope of competition on the merits. (52)

Indeed, the case-law of the Court, in my view, confirms that exclusionary conduct of a dominant undertaking which can be replicated by equally efficient competitors does not represent, in principle, conduct that may lead to anticompetitive foreclosure and therefore comes within the scope of competition on the merits. (52)

First, in the context of price-related exclusionary conduct – such as loyalty rebates, low-pricing practices in the form of selective prices or predatory prices and margin squeeze (53) – such a possibility of replication is assessed, as a general rule, but not necessarily, on the basis of the so-called ‘equally efficient competitor test’ (‘EEC test’). (54) The particular modalities of that test vary depending on the type of practice in question, but the common factor consists in examining whether a pricing practice is economically viable for the competitor of a dominant undertaking, using as a point of reference, primarily and as a general rule, the dominant undertaking’s price/cost ratio. (55) In other words, that test consists in identifying whether that conduct can be replicated by an equally efficient competitor by placing the dominant undertaking in the place of the equally efficient competitor to ascertain whether the latter would suffer exclusionary effects from the practice in question. That test is consistent with the general principle of legal certainty in that it allows a dominant undertaking to assess in advance whether particular conduct is lawful on the basis of its own costs. (56)

First, in the context of price-related exclusionary conduct – such as loyalty rebates, low-pricing practices in the form of selective prices or predatory prices and margin squeeze (53) – such a possibility of replication is assessed, as a general rule, but not necessarily, on the basis of the so-called ‘equally efficient competitor test’ (‘EEC test’). (54) The particular modalities of that test vary depending on the type of practice in question, but the common factor consists in examining whether a pricing practice is economically viable for the competitor of a dominant undertaking, using as a point of reference, primarily and as a general rule, the dominant undertaking’s price/cost ratio. (55) In other words, that test consists in identifying whether that conduct can be replicated by an equally efficient competitor by placing the dominant undertaking in the place of the equally efficient competitor to ascertain whether the latter would suffer exclusionary effects from the practice in question. That test is consistent with the general principle of legal certainty in that it allows a dominant undertaking to assess in advance whether particular conduct is lawful on the basis of its own costs. (56)

Second, as regards exclusionary practices not related to pricing – such as, for example, refusal to supply – the case-law seems to confirm the relevance of the test as regards the possibility of replication, inasmuch as a dominant undertaking’s decision to reserve for itself its own distribution network does not constitute a refusal to supply contrary to Article 102 TFEU when a competitor is able to create a second distribution network of a comparable size. In other words, there is no abuse if inputs refused by the dominant undertaking can be duplicated by equally efficient undertakings by purchasing them from other suppliers or developing them themselves. (57) Similarly, in the context of tying and bundling practices, whether it is possible to replicate a product is particularly relevant in establishing whether there is potential or actual anticompetitive foreclosure. (58)

Second, as regards exclusionary practices not related to pricing – such as, for example, refusal to supply – the case-law seems to confirm the relevance of the test as regards the possibility of replication, inasmuch as a dominant undertaking’s decision to reserve for itself its own distribution network does not constitute a refusal to supply contrary to Article 102 TFEU when a competitor is able to create a second distribution network of a comparable size. In other words, there is no abuse if inputs refused by the dominant undertaking can be duplicated by equally efficient undertakings by purchasing them from other suppliers or developing them themselves. (57) Similarly, in the context of tying and bundling practices, whether it is possible to replicate a product is particularly relevant in establishing whether there is potential or actual anticompetitive foreclosure. (58)

In the present case, the conduct at issue in the main proceedings does not, according to the AGCM, concern a pricing practice, but a complex, unlawful strategy characterised by the exploitation of data to which the Enel Group had access on account of its former statutory monopoly. It would therefore seem that that practice is not connected to a theory of price-related foreclosure and that, on account of the statutory monopoly, it was objectively impossible, before the liberalisation of the market, for competitors to replicate the strategy attributed to the appellants. It follows that the EEC test is certainly not the most appropriate test to assess the ability of equally efficient competitors to imitate the conduct of the dominant undertaking.

In the present case, the conduct at issue in the main proceedings does not, according to the AGCM, concern a pricing practice, but a complex, unlawful strategy characterised by the exploitation of data to which the Enel Group had access on account of its former statutory monopoly. It would therefore seem that that practice is not connected to a theory of price-related foreclosure and that, on account of the statutory monopoly, it was objectively impossible, before the liberalisation of the market, for competitors to replicate the strategy attributed to the appellants. It follows that the EEC test is certainly not the most appropriate test to assess the ability of equally efficient competitors to imitate the conduct of the dominant undertaking.

However, the underlying logic of the EEC test – which seeks, in essence, to estimate whether a dominant undertaking was in a position in which it was able to foresee, on the basis of data known to it, whether a competitor could, despite the conduct in question, have stayed competitive on the market operating in an economically viable way – to my mind remains relevant. Thus a test based on the logic of that test would consist in assessing whether, on the basis of information presumed to be known to the dominant undertaking, competitors could have had access, in an economically viable way, to lists that are comparable as regards their usefulness to the SEN lists. That approach also coincides with the significance attributed to the ability-to-replicate test in the context of eviction practices not related to pricing.

Accordingly, I am of the view that the objective impossibility for competitors to replicate exactly the same strategy as Enel does not preclude an examination of the actual ability of equally efficient competitors to replicate, in reasonable economic conditions and within acceptable timeframes, the practices of the dominant undertaking, for example by making use of lists that were undeniably available on the market and which contained data similar to that on the SEN lists. That examination may, to my mind, indicate whether or not Enel’s conduct is capable of producing anticompetitive exclusionary effects and, therefore, whether or not it is consistent with competition on the merits.

However, the underlying logic of the EEC test – which seeks, in essence, to estimate whether a dominant undertaking was in a position in which it was able to foresee, on the basis of data known to it, whether a competitor could, despite the conduct in question, have stayed competitive on the market operating in an economically viable way – to my mind remains relevant. Thus a test based on the logic of that test would consist in assessing whether, on the basis of information presumed to be known to the dominant undertaking, competitors could have had access, in an economically viable way, to lists that are comparable as regards their usefulness to the SEN lists. That approach also coincides with the significance attributed to the ability-to-replicate test in the context of eviction practices not related to pricing.

In the context of such an examination, which is to be carried out by the referring court, the following points are of particular relevance.

Accordingly, I am of the view that the objective impossibility for competitors to replicate exactly the same strategy as Enel does not preclude an examination of the actual ability of equally efficient competitors to replicate, in reasonable economic conditions and within acceptable timeframes, the practices of the dominant undertaking, for example by making use of lists that were undeniably available on the market and which contained data similar to that on the SEN lists. That examination may, to my mind, indicate whether or not Enel’s conduct is capable of producing anticompetitive exclusionary effects and, therefore, whether or not it is consistent with competition on the merits.

First, and with some caution, the importance of the SEN lists from a competitive point of view should be determined. In that connection I note that there is particular interest in access to data on customers in the context of a liberalisation process, both in abstract terms, in that it allows a better understanding of the market to be gained, and in practical terms, in that it allows those customers to be ‘captured’ by presenting them with offers before other providers. However, the importance of that data must also be nuanced since it must not be forgotten that the possibility to contact a customer in order to, where appropriate, make that customer an offer, does not necessarily mean that those customers will be ‘captured’ since, on the one hand, those customers will not necessarily subscribe to such offers (59) and, on the other hand, there is nothing preventing those customers from subscribing to offers from other providers at a later stage, particularly when the first contract does not engage customers for a specific period. I recall that anticompetitive effects must have a causal link with the practice at issue, in that they must be imputable to the dominant undertaking and must not be purely hypothetical. (60)

In the context of such an examination, which is to be carried out by the referring court, the following points are of particular relevance.

Second, the referring court will inevitably have to clarify whether the SEN lists were made available to competitors in a discriminatory manner, both at a practical level and regarding price, which, if they were, would constitute, in essence, a practice favouring EE. In that same respect, it seems to me relevant to assess whether the request for consent had been made by SEN in a non-discriminatory manner which was transparent as to the material consequences, in particular from the point of view of maintaining the existing supply relationship and the possibility of receiving supply offers from EE’s competitors. If discrimination was found to exist, that could corroborate the AGCM’s position that Enel’s conduct was not in accordance with competition on the merits, in that equality of opportunity was not secured as between the various economic operators. (61)

First, and with some caution, the importance of the SEN lists from a competitive point of view should be determined. In that connection I note that there is particular interest in access to data on customers in the context of a liberalisation process, both in abstract terms, in that it allows a better understanding of the market to be gained, and in practical terms, in that it allows those customers to be ‘captured’ by presenting them with offers before other providers. However, the importance of that data must also be nuanced since it must not be forgotten that the possibility to contact a customer in order to, where appropriate, make that customer an offer, does not necessarily mean that those customers will be ‘captured’ since, on the one hand, those customers will not necessarily subscribe to such offers (59) and, on the other hand, there is nothing preventing those customers from subscribing to offers from other providers at a later stage, particularly when the first contract does not engage customers for a specific period. I recall that anticompetitive effects must have a causal link with the practice at issue, in that they must be imputable to the dominant undertaking and must not be purely hypothetical. (60)

Third, I am of the view that, independently of the analysis of the discriminatory nature of the conduct, the referring court will also have to assess whether it was possible to replicate the SEN lists. Although, indeed, the exact content of those lists cannot be replicated by EE’s competitors, since those lists were compiled in the context of SEN’s public service mission, it is apparent from the case file that lists with similar content were also available on the Italian market, where a large number of undertakings are in the business of producing telemarketing lists. If the existence of alternative lists is proven, they would have effectively enabled EE’s competitors to make targeted offers for the supply of energy to customers of the protected market. In such a case, I am of the view that the referring court would have to compare those alternative lists to the SEN lists, as regards their availability, their price, their content and their geographic extent, in order to ascertain whether a competitor, even one much smaller economically than the Enel Group, through use of such lists, would actually have been able to compete effectively with EE, in an economically viable way, in respect of the same part of the contestable customer base of the protected market.

Second, the referring court will inevitably have to clarify whether the SEN lists were made available to competitors in a discriminatory manner, both at a practical level and regarding price, which, if they were, would constitute, in essence, a practice favouring EE. In that same respect, it seems to me relevant to assess whether the request for consent had been made by SEN in a non-discriminatory manner which was transparent as to the material consequences, in particular from the point of view of maintaining the existing supply relationship and the possibility of receiving supply offers from EE’s competitors. If discrimination was found to exist, that could corroborate the AGCM’s position that Enel’s conduct was not in accordance with competition on the merits, in that equality of opportunity was not secured as between the various economic operators. (61)

If the referring court takes the view that those alternative lists were capable of offering the same opportunities as the SEN lists, assuming that Enel must have been aware both of the existence of those alternative lists and of their content, it seems to me that it could be concluded that any potential risk of foreclosure of the relevant market was due not to Enel’s actions but to the negligence of its competitors, which did not act competitively in order to capture customers of the protected market. In other words, the SEN lists would not have been capable of conferring on the Enel Group the significant competitive advantage observed by the AGCM on account of their ability to be replicated. In such a case, the ability of the conduct at issue to restrict competition could be proven, with the result that the conduct at issue in the main proceedings would come within the scope of competition on the merits.

Third, I am of the view that, independently of the analysis of the discriminatory nature of the conduct, the referring court will also have to assess whether it was possible to replicate the SEN lists. Although, indeed, the exact content of those lists cannot be replicated by EE’s competitors, since those lists were compiled in the context of SEN’s public service mission, it is apparent from the case file that lists with similar content were also available on the Italian market, where a large number of undertakings are in the business of producing telemarketing lists. If the existence of alternative lists is proven, they would have effectively enabled EE’s competitors to make targeted offers for the supply of energy to customers of the protected market. In such a case, I am of the view that the referring court would have to compare those alternative lists to the SEN lists, as regards their availability, their price, their content and their geographic extent, in order to ascertain whether a competitor, even one much smaller economically than the Enel Group, through use of such lists, would actually have been able to compete effectively with EE, in an economically viable way, in respect of the same part of the contestable customer base of the protected market.

By contrast, if it appears from the national court’s analysis that the potential for commercial exploitation of those alternative lists was minimal and that only the SEN lists enabled, for example, a customer of the protected market to be immediately identified, the (potential) exclusionary effect would be principally attributable to Enel, which, if it were held that it acted in a discriminatory and non-transparent manner, would have effectively acted in a manner that is not covered by competition on the merits. Moreover, it should be borne in mind that the fact that competitors can limit or obviate the effects of Enel’s conduct through the use of alternative lists does not, in the light of Enel’s market power, prevent the conduct at issue from being just as capable of having anticompetitive effects. In other words, the fact that alternative lists exist is certainly relevant, but is not, in itself, decisive.

If the referring court takes the view that those alternative lists were capable of offering the same opportunities as the SEN lists, assuming that Enel must have been aware both of the existence of those alternative lists and of their content, it seems to me that it could be concluded that any potential risk of foreclosure of the relevant market was due not to Enel’s actions but to the negligence of its competitors, which did not act competitively in order to capture customers of the protected market. In other words, the SEN lists would not have been capable of conferring on the Enel Group the significant competitive advantage observed by the AGCM on account of their ability to be replicated. In such a case, the ability of the conduct at issue to restrict competition could be proven, with the result that the conduct at issue in the main proceedings would come within the scope of competition on the merits.

In the light of the foregoing considerations, I suggest that the answer to the first question should be that a practice adopted by an undertaking in a dominant position, irrespective of its lawfulness under branches of law other than competition law, may not be characterised as abusive within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU solely on the basis of its exclusionary effect in the relevant market, since such conduct should not be equated with a restrictive effect on competition unless it is shown that the undertaking has employed methods or means different from those which come within the scope of competition on the merits. In principle, an exclusionary practice which can be replicated by competitors in an economically viable way does not represent conduct that may lead to anticompetitive foreclosure and thus comes within the scope of competition on the merits.

By contrast, if it appears from the national court’s analysis that the potential for commercial exploitation of those alternative lists was minimal and that only the SEN lists enabled, for example, a customer of the protected market to be immediately identified, the (potential) exclusionary effect would be principally attributable to Enel, which, if it were held that it acted in a discriminatory and non-transparent manner, would have effectively acted in a manner that is not covered by competition on the merits. Moreover, it should be borne in mind that the fact that competitors can limit or obviate the effects of Enel’s conduct through the use of alternative lists does not, in the light of Enel’s market power, prevent the conduct at issue from being just as capable of having anticompetitive effects. In other words, the fact that alternative lists exist is certainly relevant, but is not, in itself, decisive.

By its second question, the referring court asks the Court, in essence, to clarify whether Article 102 TFEU is intended to protect consumers or to protect the competitive structure of the market and, depending on the answer to that question, to determine the scope of the evidence that is needed in order for an exclusionary practice to be classed as abusive.

In the light of the foregoing considerations, I suggest that the answer to the first question should be that a practice adopted by an undertaking in a dominant position, irrespective of its lawfulness under branches of law other than competition law, may not be characterised as abusive within the meaning of Article 102 TFEU solely on the basis of its exclusionary effect in the relevant market, since such conduct should not be equated with a restrictive effect on competition unless it is shown that the undertaking has employed methods or means different from those which come within the scope of competition on the merits. In principle, an exclusionary practice which can be replicated by competitors in an economically viable way does not represent conduct that may lead to anticompetitive foreclosure and thus comes within the scope of competition on the merits.

AIGET disputes the admissibility of this question on two grounds. First, the answer is clear from the settled case-law of the Court. Second, the question is not relevant to the resolution of the dispute, given that the conduct in question affected both the structure of the market, namely the competing suppliers, and consumers, namely the customers of the protected market, who found themselves prevented from choosing from among the services provided on the free market.

By its second question, the referring court asks the Court, in essence, to clarify whether Article 102 TFEU is intended to protect consumers or to protect the competitive structure of the market and, depending on the answer to that question, to determine the scope of the evidence that is needed in order for an exclusionary practice to be classed as abusive.

Those objections – should the Court decide to address them expressly, in the absence of a formal claim for a finding that the question is inadmissible – should, in my view, be dismissed.

Indeed, first, it should be recalled that even when there is case-law resolving the point of law at issue, national courts remain entirely at liberty to bring a matter before the Court if they consider it appropriate to do so. (62) Thus, the fact that the Court has interpreted Article 102 TFEU in the past cannot in itself cause the questions referred in the present case to be inadmissible. Moreover, the referring court claims that the answer is not obvious, since diverging opinions have been expressed by the Commission, according to which Article 102 TFEU is aimed at maximising consumer well-being, (63) and by the Court, according to which that provision is designed to preserve the structure of competition, independently of any disadvantage caused to consumers. (64)

AIGET disputes the admissibility of this question on two grounds. First, the answer is clear from the settled case-law of the Court. Second, the question is not relevant to the resolution of the dispute, given that the conduct in question affected both the structure of the market, namely the competing suppliers, and consumers, namely the customers of the protected market, who found themselves prevented from choosing from among the services provided on the free market.

Second, as regards the relevance of the question, it should be borne in mind that it is for the national court alone to determine both the need for a preliminary ruling in order to enable it to deliver judgment and the relevance of the questions submitted. (65) In the present case, the referring court justifies the necessity of the second question by explaining, in essence, that the answer to that question will determine the scope of the evidence that is required. (66) Therefore, in my view, that question has a direct relationship with the subject matter of the dispute in the main proceedings and it is not hypothetical.

Those objections – should the Court decide to address them expressly, in the absence of a formal claim for a finding that the question is inadmissible – should, in my view, be dismissed.

Indeed, first, it should be recalled that even when there is case-law resolving the point of law at issue, national courts remain entirely at liberty to bring a matter before the Court if they consider it appropriate to do so. (62) Thus, the fact that the Court has interpreted Article 102 TFEU in the past cannot in itself cause the questions referred in the present case to be inadmissible. Moreover, the referring court claims that the answer is not obvious, since diverging opinions have been expressed by the Commission, according to which Article 102 TFEU is aimed at maximising consumer well-being, (63) and by the Court, according to which that provision is designed to preserve the structure of competition, independently of any disadvantage caused to consumers. (64)

The second question submitted for a preliminary ruling consists of two parts:

the first part seeks to establish what interest is protected by Article 102 TFEU. Two possibilities are contemplated here which the referring court presents as alternatives, namely ‘the maximisation of consumer protection’ or ‘the preservation of the structure of competition in the market’;

Second, as regards the relevance of the question, it should be borne in mind that it is for the national court alone to determine both the need for a preliminary ruling in order to enable it to deliver judgment and the relevance of the questions submitted. (65) In the present case, the referring court justifies the necessity of the second question by explaining, in essence, that the answer to that question will determine the scope of the evidence that is required. (66) Therefore, in my view, that question has a direct relationship with the subject matter of the dispute in the main proceedings and it is not hypothetical.

the second part seeks to determine the consequences in terms of evidence of the relationship between those two objectives of Article 102 TFEU.

(a) The first part

The second question submitted for a preliminary ruling consists of two parts:

Before dealing with the substance of the first part, some preliminary remarks are called for.

– the first part seeks to establish what interest is protected by Article 102 TFEU. Two possibilities are contemplated here which the referring court presents as alternatives, namely ‘the maximisation of consumer protection’ or ‘the preservation of the structure of competition in the market’;

First, the referring court will have to clarify whether the SEN lists were made available to competitors in a discriminatory manner, both at a practical level and regarding price, which, if they were, would constitute, in essence, a practice favouring EE. In that same respect, it seems to me relevant to assess whether the request for consent had been made by SEN in a non-discriminatory manner which was transparent as to the material consequences, in particular from the point of view of maintaining the existing supply relationship and the possibility of receiving supply offers from EE’s competitors. If discrimination was found to exist, that could corroborate the AGCM’s position that Enel’s conduct was not in accordance with competition on the merits, in that equality of opportunity was not secured as between the various economic operators. (61)

– the second part seeks to determine the consequences in terms of evidence of the relationship between those two objectives of Article 102 TFEU.

Second, I am of the view that, independently of the analysis of the discriminatory nature of the conduct, the referring court will also have to assess whether it was possible to replicate the SEN lists. Although, indeed, the exact content of those lists cannot be replicated by EE’s competitors, since those lists were compiled in the context of SEN’s public service mission, it is apparent from the case file that lists with similar content were also available on the Italian market, where a large number of undertakings are in the business of producing telemarketing lists. If the existence of alternative lists is proven, they would have effectively enabled EE’s competitors to make targeted offers for the supply of energy to customers of the protected market. In such a case, I am of the view that the referring court would have to compare those alternative lists to the SEN lists, as regards their availability, their price, their content and their geographic extent, in order to ascertain whether a competitor, even one much smaller economically than the Enel Group, through use of such lists, would actually have been able to compete effectively with EE, in an economically viable way, in respect of the same part of the contestable customer base of the protected market.

(a) The first part

If the referring court takes the view that those alternative lists were capable of offering the same opportunities as the SEN lists, assuming that Enel must have been aware both of the existence of those alternative lists and of their content, it seems to me that it could be concluded that any potential risk of foreclosure of the relevant market was due not to Enel’s actions but to the negligence of its competitors, which did not act competitively in order to capture customers of the protected market. In other words, the SEN lists would not have been capable of conferring on the Enel Group the significant competitive advantage observed by the AGCM on account of their ability to be replicated. In such a case, the ability of the conduct at issue to restrict competition could be proven, with the result that the conduct at issue in the main proceedings would come within the scope of competition on the merits.

Before dealing with the substance of the first part, some preliminary remarks are called for.

By contrast, if it appears from the national court’s analysis that the potential for commercial exploitation of those alternative lists was minimal and that only the SEN lists enabled, for example, a customer of the protected market to be immediately identified, the (potential) exclusionary effect would be principally attributable to Enel, which, if it were held that it acted in a discriminatory and non-transparent manner, would have effectively acted in a manner that is not covered by competition on the merits. Moreover, it should be borne in mind that the fact that competitors can limit or obviate the effects of Enel’s conduct through the use of alternative lists does not, in the light of Enel’s market power, prevent the conduct at issue from being just as capable of having anticompetitive effects. In other words, the fact that alternative lists exist is certainly relevant, but is not, in itself, decisive.

EurLex Case Law

AI-Powered Case Law Search

Query in any language with multilingual search
Access EUR-Lex and EU Commission case law
See relevant paragraphs highlighted instantly

Get Instant Answers to Your Legal Questions

Cancel your subscription anytime, no questions asked.Start 14-Day Free Trial

At Modern Legal, we’re building the world’s best search engine for legal professionals. Access EU and global case law with AI-powered precision, saving you time and delivering relevant insights instantly.

Contact Us

Tivolska cesta 48, 1000 Ljubljana, Slovenia